The Reserve Bank of India committee on household finance (Ramadorai Committee) has commented on the low pension participation of Indian households. This is something that several committees constituted by the Pension Fund Regulatory and Development Authority (PFRDA) have also worried about. The Ramadorai Committee as well as the PFRDA committees
have suggested increasing the incentives of distributors (and fund
managers) to incentivise people to join the National Pension System (NPS). But before we tinker with the basic framework and philosophy behind the NPS, it is useful to agree on what low pension coverage means and the place of the NPS in such a framework.
Across the world, pension participation
typically means coverage in plans that are either mandatory or
universally provided by the state through tax revenues. Voluntary
coverage incentivised through tax breaks is in addition to these
universal or mandatory programmes. In India we have three main kinds of pension schemes.
The first is the NPS, which is mandatory for civil servants. The second
is the Employees’ Provident Fund Organisation (EPFO), mandatory for
employees in firms of 20 or more people. The third is the Indira Gandhi
National Old Age Pension Scheme (IGNOAPS), a pension given to the destitute elderly. When we say low pension coverage,
we usually mean that a large number of citizens do not have access to
any of these programmes and are left to themselves to find ways to
finance consumption in old age.
Savings, on the other hand, are voluntary and can be influenced by
various factors such as risk aversion, lifecycle needs, access to
products and financial literacy. Just because an individual does not
have a pension account
does not necessarily mean that she has no savings to finance
consumption in old age. In fact, as we are talking about voluntary
savings, the first-order question is whether people save enough and not
whether they save through plans called pensions.
It is in this context of voluntary savings versus mandatory programmes that the pension debate in India needs to be placed. When we say we want to increase pension participation,
do we want to increase participation through the mandating savings
route? Or do we want to incentivise people to save into specific pension products?
We have limited evidence on the question of whether households in India
end up with too few resources in old age and how they finance their
consumption as a consequence. International evidence shows that
households are myopic; this has motivated the setting up of mandatory pension programmes.
The really poor households in India are unlikely to have any savings
and would require state support in the form of cash transfers. The
Ramadorai Committee report shows that households that have savings
over-invest in physical assets, in general. Households rely — perhaps
over-rely — on children for old-age support. Thus, low financial savings
and suboptimal investments suggest a case for mandatory savings in the NPS. However, this can be difficult to enforce and in a large informal sector such as India may not be possible to do immediately.
This brings us to the question of voluntary savings. It is tempting to
go in the direction of increasing distribution charges to lure more
people into the NPS on
a voluntary basis. High incentives in other products have not given us
very high participation — in some products such as insurance, they have
certainly given us very low persistence. Consumer protection problems
are pervasive in retail finance, as the Ramadorai Committee report also
notes. By increasing the fees on the NPS we
are making it more like a mutual fund; it is not clear why we should
head in this direction, when a mutual fund industry already exists.
Allowing NPS fund managers to market the NPS also
opens the floodgates for increasing charges and diluting it for
existing customers, most of whom are there as a result of the mandatory
civil services reform.
Ultimately, the way to a higher pension coverage is to find ways to mandate pension participation
and simultaneously have state subsidies in the form of cash transfers
for the really poor. This requires action on three fronts. First, we
need to improve programmes such as the IGNOAPS. Only when this happens
will the destitute elderly have access to a pension.
Second, we need to consider ways to mandate the NPS, perhaps with a
much lower contribution rate than 20 per cent to firms with less than 20
employees and to the self-employed. Across the world, this has been the
path to pension coverage; it should be no different in India.
Third, we need to improve the existing schemes and arrangements. For example, we need to facilitate giving existing EPFO employees a choice between the Employees’ Provident Fund (EPF) and the NPS. We also need to deal with the funding issues of the Employees’ Pension Scheme (EPS). We need to improve the draw-down phase of the NPS so that people are able to translate the accumulations into a steady flow of monthly pension income. Questions of tax parity between the various schemes need to be resolved so that one is not unfairly penalised.
The OASIS Committee Report commissioned by the Ministry of Social
Justice and Empowerment in 1998, that was the genesis of the NPS, had
anticipated consumer protection issues seen in other retail financial
products. The NPS design
of separating fund management and record-keeping of an auction-based
mechanism for discovering fund management fees and passive management
frontally addresses these concerns. It is crucial to continue with this,
as a good low-cost product is a prerequisite if we are to coerce
citizens to save for old age.
(This first appeared in the Business Standard on 5th September, 2017)
(This first appeared in the Business Standard on 5th September, 2017)